Who pays the highest income tax?

Fiscal Affairs Division
Page 21 

Click for larger graph

Focusing on “headline” rates of tax can easily generate misleading conclusions about how much marginal income tax people pay and about the effect taxes can have on earner behaviour. In the second of their two-part series on income taxes, Flid de Kam and Chiara Bronchi explain why.
It is not always high earners who pay the highest marginal rates of taxes on income. This assertion may appear to contradict what one would expect of progressive tax systems. Yet, in most OECD countries many individuals in low- to middle-income brackets find themselves exposed to higher marginal rates -- that is the rate applied to the last additional dollar, yen or franc earned -- than even the very rich. The question is why?Part of the answer lies in "bubbles", which are humps in the structure of taxes on income. Bubbles can develop in cases where income is subject to both personal income tax and social security contributions. The tax base of those contributions may be identical or similar to that used for personal income tax. But unlike for income tax, a ceiling or cap often applies; earnings above that ceiling are not subject to social security contributions. A bubble appears if the combined marginal rate of income tax and "capped" social security contributions exceeds the marginal income tax rate applicable to income earned above that contributions ceiling.For example, take a country that imposes social security contributions at a flat rate of 15% on the first 50,000 units of income. Also, suppose the first 25,000 units earned are subject to 10% personal income tax, the second 25,000 units is taxed at 20%, and all income over 50,000 is taxed at the top rate of 30%. To judge by the headline rate alone, the latter rate of 30% would seem like the highest of the lot. But in practice it is those with taxable income in the middle bracket who pay the highest marginal rate, since the marginal income tax and social security add up to 35% of their additional earnings. But taxpayers in the highest bracket are not required to pay the 15% social security contribution and so only pay 30% on their highest earnings.But bubbles do not just show up in "all-in" rates of the combined taxes on income. Occasionally, they appear in standard personal income tax schedules as well. In the second half of the 1980s the US federal income tax had such a rate structure. At the time, income in the first bracket was taxed at 15% and income in the top bracket at 28%. It follows that tax relief for high-income earners, which is determined by the marginal tax rate, was almost twice the tax relief for low-income earners. To recoup the higher tax relief for well-off taxpayers, lawmakers introduced a new 33% bracket which they sandwiched between the low and high brackets. The new middle rate worked like this. Suppose for the sake of illustration that the personal exemption on income tax was $4,000 across the board.Under the old structure before the 33% band was created the tax bill of low-income earners would have been reduced by $600, since with the exemption they would not have had to pay the 15% tax on that $4,000. The tax bill for those in the highest taxed bracket would have been slashed by $1,120, because they would have been exempt from paying 28% on their highest $4,000 of income. The difference of $520 in favour of higher earners was clawed back by inserting a middle bracket of $10,400 taxed at 33%, that means 5% more tax to pay than before, or $520. So, although the tax relief for the highest earners remained at 28%, or $1,120, by taxing middle earnings more, the new bracket effectively balanced the tax relief for those in the low and the top brackets at $600. The rates of the federal income tax in Switzerland show a similar "bubble" today.A job can make you poorerAnother rather curious situation which does not show up when studying headline rates is that low earners can find themselves confronted with very high marginal tax rates, in some rare cases exceeding 100%. The reason for this is that lower earners not only pay more tax when their income goes up, but in many cases they lose part of their means-tested tax relief, subsidies and benefits as well. The loss of this income acts as an "implicit" tax at the margin. The rational response of workers who find themselves in this situation is to reduce the number of hours they work. Their gross wage would of course be lower if they did, but in return they would pay less tax and receive more means-tested subsidies and benefits. As a result, their net disposable income would increase despite putting in fewer hours.This type of situation occurs to varying degrees in different OECD countries, depending on the peculiarities of various social protection programmes. Take the example of an unemployed couple with two young children. Suppose that after five years' unemployment, one of them takes up a lowly paid job. In Finland or Sweden net income in and out of work would be the same in that case, since each unit of income earned is cancelled out by a unit of benefits foregone once employment is taken up. In other words, there is an implicit tax rate of 100%. In the case of Denmark and the Czech Republic, the implicit rate in a similar case would be almost 100%, and in Germany and the United Kingdom it would be around 80%.In France and the United States the implicit rate would be about 50%, since half the increase in earnings is wiped out by a loss of benefits. In Japan, the implicit tax actually exceeds 140%, meaning our one-earner couple would be worse off with the new job than without it. What's more, they may have to be wary when it comes to staying in the job itself, since small wage increases can expose low-wage earners to high implicit tax rates as their means-tested benefits get cut further.As the next chart shows, the "all-in" top rates of the combined taxes on personal income may also vary by type of income. Labour income is more heavily taxed if it is subject to contributions earmarked to finance employee social insurance. Rates of personal income tax proper may also differ, depending on the type of earnings. For example, capital income, which is often an important revenue component of the well-off, is often not subject to most social security contributions. In addition, over the past fifteen years a number of OECD countries have introduced low, flat rates for certain types of capital income, notably interest and dividend earnings. This is the case for Belgium, the Czech Republic, Greece, Hungary, Italy, Poland and the Nordic countries. Flat rates on capital income can reduce the overall progressiveness of the income tax and undermine its redistributive effect. Moreover, any examination of the highest statutory income tax rates that does not also take these low, flat rates on capital income into account tends to overstate the tax burden of high earners. For larger graph click hereWhy were these flat rates introduced? One explanation is that they were a response to growing pressures from cross-border tax competition. Financial capital, being highly mobile, tends to flow to those jurisdictions where it is taxed at the lowest rates. To address capital flight, tax policy-makers may decide to reduce the domestic tax burden on capital income. The moves were also part of a more general strategy designed to lower the efficiency costs of taxation by reducing rates, while at the same time spreading taxes more widely along the capital income tax base.Planning privilegeAnother point to remember when looking at "statutory" tax rates, which are the tax rates as set by law, is that many high-income earners actually escape paying them. There is of course no automatic reason to assume that high-income groups are more inclined to evade taxes than are low to middle income groups simply because they are better off. Nevertheless, it is true that the self-employed, who make up a significant proportion of high-income earners, are generally in a better position than other groups of taxpayers, particularly those who are taxed at source, to limit their tax obligations. This they can do legally, by using tax breaks for business, and illegally, by under-reporting their income (see Spotlight on Taxation in Observer 215, January 1999).Tax planning is often used to take the bite out of high rates. If properly done, high-income earners may see their taxable income shrink, their tax bills fall and their disposable income rise. For example, in some countries the corporation income tax rate is substantially lower than the top income tax rate, providing the self-employed with a strong incentive to cloak their business in a corporate veil while paying themselves only a small director's salary. In the Netherlands the gap between the corporation and top personal income tax rates is 25 points -- 35% and 60% respectively. Another practice is to transform taxable capital income into tax-exempt capital gains when the latter are exempted from personal income tax.The fact that tax planning exists shows that there is much more to taxation than the "headline" rates suggest. Building a full and accurate picture of income taxes, particularly where marginal rates are concerned, requires information on fiscal and social security programmes, as we have shown in this mini-series of articles. In fact, it is only by looking at such areas as all-in rates, income-related relief and benefits, and other taxes, such as low rates on capital income, that we can begin to appreciate how truly wonderful the world of taxation really is.BibliographyThe data in this article are drawn from the OECD Tax Data Base.daf.contact@oecd.org.©OECD Observer 217-218, Summer 1999


Economic data

E-Newsletter

Stay up-to-date with the latest news from the OECD by signing up for our e-newsletter :

Twitter feed

Suscribe now

<b>Subscribe now!</b>

To receive your exclusive print editions delivered to you directly


Online edition
Previous editions

Don't miss

  • How sustainable is the ocean as a source of economic development? The Ocean Economy in 2030 examines the risks and uncertainties surrounding the future development of ocean industries, the innovations required in science and technology to support their progress, their potential contribution to green growth and some of the implications for ocean management.
  • OECD Environment Director Simon Upton presented a talk at Imperial College London on 21 April 2016. With the world awash in surplus oil and prices languishing around US$40 per barrel, how can governments step up efforts to transform the world’s energy systems in line with the Paris Agreement?
  • Happy 10th birthday to Twitter. This 2008 OECD Observer interview with Henry Copeland said you’d do well.
  • The OECD Gender Initiative examines existing barriers to gender equality in education, employment, and entrepreneurship. The gender portal monitors the progress made by governments to promote gender equality in both OECD and non-OECD countries and provides good practices based on analytical tools and reliable data.
  • Once migrants reach Europe, countries face integration challenge: OECD's Thomas Liebig speaks to NPR's Audie Cornish.
  • “Un Automne à Paris”: listen (and read) this sad yet uplifting new song by jazzman Ibrahim Maalouf and pop singer Louane that will be launched on 11 January in honour of the victims of the murderous attacks on the French capital in 2015 and as a tribute to love and liberty in this City of Light.

  • Secretary-General Angel Gurria on CNBC: Developed vs developing nations at COP21

  • Message from the International Space Station to COP21

  • COP21 Will Get Agreement With Teeth: OECD Secretary-General Angel Gurría on Bloomberg

  • The carbon clock is ticking: OECD’s Gurría on CNBC

  • If we want to reach zero net emissions by the end of the century, we must align our policies for a low-carbon economy, put a price on carbon everywhere, spend less subsidising fossil fuels and invest more in clean energy. OECD at #COP21 – OECD statement for #COP21
  • They are green and local --It’s a new generation of entrepreneurs in Kenya with big dreams of sustainable energy and the drive to see their innovative technologies throughout Africa. blogs.worldbank.org
  • Pole to Paris Project
  • Black carbon causes millions of deaths every year and contributes to the warming of the planet. The United Nations Environment Programme explains how reducing black carbon can save lives and help combat climate change.
  • In order to face global warming, Asia needs at least $40 billion per year, derived from both the public and private sector. Read how to bridge the climate financing gap on the Asian Bank of Development's website.
  • How can cities fight climate change?
    Discover projects in Denmark, Canada, Australia, Japan and Mexico.
  • Climate: What's changed, what hasn't, what we can do about it.
    Lecture by OECD Secretary-General Angel Gurría, hosted by the London School of Economics and Aviva Investors in association with ClimateWise, London, UK, 3 July 2015.
  • French Economy Minister Emmanuel Macron came to the OECD on 18 September for a webcast discussion on economic reforms, inequality and the outlook, with OECD Secretary-General Angel Gurría. You can watch the event by clicking on the photo.

  • Climate change: “We should not disagree when scientists tell us we have a window of opportunity–10-15 years–to turn this thing around” argues Senator Bernie Sanders.

  • In the long-run, the EU benefits from migration, says OECD Head of International Migration Division Jean-Christophe Dumont.
  • Is technological progress slowing down? Is it speeding up? At the OECD, we believe the research from our Future of ‪Productivity‬ project helps to resolve this paradox.
  • An employee prepares breakfast in front of the Eiffel tower at the Parisian luxury hotel Le Plaza Athenee. Nowhere in the world has more accommodation available on Airbnb than Paris. Now the home-sharing website that has transformed budget travel is giving super-deluxe hotels a fright too.
    ©REUTERS/Stephane Mahe
  • Is inequality bad for growth? That redistribution boosts economies is not established by the evidence says FT economics editor Chris Giles. Read more on www.ft.com.
  • Low interest rates here to stay for half a century, says OECD director Adrian Blundell-Wignall.
  • Bill Gates visited the OECD on 26 June. He met with the Secretary-General Angel Gurría to discuss areas of collaboration with his foundation and participated at a briefing session on official development assistance modernisation with OECD experts.
  • The People’s Republic of China decided to enhance longstanding collaboration with the OECD and to join the OECD Development Centre, in a historic visit by Chinese Premier Li Keqiang on 1 July to the OECD in Paris.
    Read about it on OECD.org
  • Catherine Mann, OECD Chief Economist, explains on Bloomberg why "too much bank lending can slow economic growth".
  • Interested in a career in Paris at the OECD? The OECD is a major international organisation, with a mission to build better policies for better lives. With our hub based in one of the world's global cities and offices across continents, find out more at www.oecd.org/careers .
  • Come va la vita in Italia? How's life in Italy? The OECD Better Life Index is an interactive online platform in seven languages that goes beyond GDP by offering important insights into measuring well-being and quality of life. Try it for yourself!

Most Popular Articles

Poll

What issue are you most concerned about in 2015?

Euro crisis
Unemployment
Global warming
International conflict
Other

OECD Insights Blog

NOTE: All signed articles in the OECD Observer express the opinions of the authors
and do not necessarily represent the official views of OECD member countries.

All rights reserved. OECD 2016